From: joedees@bellsouth.net
Date: Sun 02 Mar 2003 - 17:51:34 GMT
Looking Inside the Brains of the Stingy
Source: New York Times
Author: Virginia Postrel
Dated: 2003-02-27
HERE's a game economists play: Player 1 has $10 and can give
any dollar amount to Player 2. Player 2 can either accept or reject
it. If Player 2 accepts, they both keep the money. If Player 2
rejects it, neither player gets anything.
What should the players do? Arguably, Player 2 should accept
whatever is offered, since some money is better than none. Player
1 should thus offer as little as possible: $1. That strategy is the
standard game-theory equilibrium.
But that's not necessarily what happens when real people play this
"ultimatum game" in laboratory settings with real money on the
line. Faced with low-ball offers, many Player 2's reject them. And
many Player 1's make more generous offers, often nearly half the
money.
"About half the subjects that we observed played according to the
way the game theory said people should play, and about half
didn't," said Kevin McCabe, an economist and director of the
Behavioral and Neuroeconomics Laboratory at George Mason
University.
The Player 1's who do not follow the presumably rational strategy
often wind up better off. Even without communicating with
fellow players, they are able to cooperate for mutual benefit.
Why do people react differently to the same situation? And why
do so many people give up money to punish anonymous
cheapskates?
Experimental economists have mapped out these anomalies and
tested how much they affect economic interactions. Now a new
field, called neuroeconomics, is using the tools of neuroscience to
find the underlying biological mechanisms that lead people to act,
or not act, according to economic theory.
In neuroeconomics, volunteers go through exercises developed by
experimental economists studying trust or risk. Instead of simply
observing subjects' behavior, however, researchers use imaging
technologies, like M.R.I.'s, to see which brain areas are active
during the experiment.
Researchers at Princeton, for instance, have found that receiving
low-ball offers stimulates the part of the brain associated with
disgust. "They can predict with good reliability, from looking at
the brain, what a person will do," said Colin F. Camerer, an
economist at the California Institute of Technology. "People
whose brains are showing lots of disgust will reject offers."
Professor Camerer says looking inside the brain's "black box" is
like looking inside a company. Traditionally, economists treated a
company as a largely automatic "production function" that turns
labor, capital and resources into output. Over the last several
decades, however, many economists have turned their attention to
understanding companies' internal workings. Most prominently,
"agency theory" examines how companies can be governed to
encourage employees (the "agents") to pursue the goals of the
owners, rather than their personal agendas.
This research hasn't replaced the production-function approach,
but it has enriched economists' understanding of company
behavior. Neuroeconomists want to do something similar for how
individuals make economic choices.
"Neuroeconomics could be to consumer theory what agency
theory is to the production-function approach," Professor Camerer
said.
While many economists remain skeptical, neuroscientists have
welcomed the interest.
"Anyone working with the brain likes this approach because
economists have these nicely defined behavioral models," said
Paul Zak, an economist and director of the Center for
Neuroeconomics Studies at Claremont Graduate University.
Neuroscientists do experiments like looking at which parts of the
brain are active when someone looks at photographs and decides
which faces are trustworthy. Neuroeconomists don't just ask
people to use their imaginations, though ” they have subjects
play laboratory games to find out what happens in real
interactions.
Professor Zak and his colleagues study trust with a variation of the
ultimatum game. Each player receives $10. Player 1 gets an
additional $10. Players interact anonymously over computers.
Player 1 can send any whole-dollar amount to Player 2. Whatever
he sends is tripled, so a $5 gift turns into $15. Finally, Player 2 can
return some of the money to Player 1.
If Player 1 expects Player 2 not to send any money in return,
Player 1 will keep the initial stake. That's the game's standard
equilibrium.
"In fact," Professor Zak said, "most people send about half of their
stake to Player 2. They're signaling that they want to trust them."
In response, about 75 percent of the Player 2's return some money,
making both better off.
"Even though we can't see each other and we don't know each
other, we understand the other person as a human being,"
Professor Zak said. Extrapolating from animal results, he
hypothesized that the hormone oxytocin, which is associated with
social bonding, might play a role.
"When you read the studies on lower mammals," he said,
"everything suggests that this is a candidate to induce
trustworthiness because it's something that you would not
consciously be aware of and yet it would influence decision
making."
Researchers tested each subject's blood for eight different
hormones right after the person made the decision about whether
to send money. For Player 1, no hormone appeared to make a
difference. But the more money the Player 2's received, the higher
their oxytocin, even after controlling for factors like age, sex and
menstrual cycle timing. The higher the oxytocin, the more money
each Player 2 returned.
That response didn't correlate with various personality measures.
"It's not that these people who returned more money are just
nicer," Professor Zak said.
Neuroeconomists caution that their research is just starting. But
that does not reduce their enthusiasm.
"For me, it's just an extremely exciting area in terms of potential,"
Professor McCabe said. "There's always new findings every day."
===============================================================
This was distributed via the memetics list associated with the
Journal of Memetics - Evolutionary Models of Information Transmission
For information about the journal and the list (e.g. unsubscribing)
see: http://www.cpm.mmu.ac.uk/jom-emit
This archive was generated by hypermail 2.1.5 : Sun 02 Mar 2003 - 17:47:53 GMT